While interesting, this sort of approach starts with wrong premises, such as the simple existence of a singular quantity of "money" at any given time, or that people spend money sufficiently randomly.
If any of these things - and these things being what distinguishes social interactions and human behavior from particles - were the case, we'd have "solved" our economic modeling issues long ago.
From my perspective (economist with prior math background), what makes the economic interaction of humans interesting and hard, is precisely that these interactions can not be aggregated (in a well-defined manner) to simple statistical or behavioral laws - be it distributions or representations, even if certain outcome distributions are observable.
To my knowledge, econophysics - despite the strong marketing effort - has yet to produce new insights into the actual economy (and it has been going on since the at least twenty years).
I think this is not surprising. The economics research effort does not lack in mathematical sophistication, even if physicists like to believe that. In fact, in terms of strategic interaction, behavioral patterns and epistemology, I think the economic models are well ahead of physics models for describing behavior. But - no one is really all that close if the level of aggregation is high. That means, macroeconomics and matters of money supply.
As an economist with a background in mathematics and physics I very much appreciated ‘econophysics’ and associated efforts, but a short while into my foray I began to realize that economics is afflicted with a dearth of conserved quantities. Physics has plenty of these (sometimes absolute, sometimes approximate) laws of conservation (conservation of energy, conservation of mass-energy, conservation of linear/angular momentum, et cetera) and these laws of conservation are critically important in constraining the dynamics a system can adhere to and thus constitute a kind of ‘shortcut’ that allows apparently intractable problems to be deftly solved by putting these constraints to masterful use. Economics has none of this. Even the apparently solid concept of ‘wealth’ (even in its weaker relative form) upon closer inspection has no fundamental basis: transactions between two parties can affect the market value of an asset and therefore increase or decrease the wealth of all of those who own (or owe) such assets.
The field therefore rapidly decayed into a form of “computational economics”. This might appear similar to “computational physics” and its use of finite element models and massively parallel simulations of particle systems to solve fluid dynamics problems. Trouble is, those systems are built up from elements that respond to the net of extant forces acting upon them, whereas in economics agents can and do act on the basis of what they expect those forces might be in the future. Self-fulfilling prophecies are “very much a thing” in economic and financial phenomenology: bubbles, crashes, recessions, booms, the whole business cycle itself...
Add to that that some actors, even very significant ones, in those markets might have really weird utility functions — for example, central banks seek not to maximise their utility — and that some agents are not rational at all (noise-traders, entrepreneurs misreading trends, & cetera) and you have another big flaw in the framework.
I also appreciate any methodological approach, if it seemed otherwise people excuse this.
But I am reasonably disappointed by the progress of econophysics given its implied ambition back then.
If there are physicists or mathematicians interested in economics, I would recommend two things.
First, delve deep into equilibrium analysis under uncertainty, game theory and mechanisms design and strategic interaction with externalities (e.g. social networks), to understand the "mathematical" and mechanical difficulties of modeling strategic human behavior under limited information. Pay ESPECIALLY attention to aggregation, e.g. when an outcome distribution implies behavior that we can influence, or when such behavior actually aggregates to overall outcomes.
Second, actually read into sociology and perhaps psychology. Here, you want to see how history dependence, the fluidity of meaning, institutions and the endogeneity of goals, may influence behavior. Behavioral econ and some experiments also.
If you, with these difficulties in mind, want to improve upon economic modeling, you are more than welcome.
But please, don't just rename the variables in a physics model.
Not really true. Econophysics, which is composed almost entirely of physicists, has not really panned out in any way.
One of the biggest criticisms of economics is faith in complex mathematical models without solid foundations or conserved quantities like in physics. Econophysics doubles down on this. It's not the right direction.
It's panned out in the sense that it earned them funding and prestige, which is the aim of economics (as opposed to investigating truth, which is the aim of physics/science).
Speaking as a physical scientist, that is a really unhelpful and bizarre opinion. Many areas of physical science, especially medicine, are facing a replication crisis due to shoddy stats themselves. And it's not like the goal of physical science academics isn't also funding and prestige (have you BEEN in academia?).
Every scientific field has its problems. Arrogantly dismissing economics while assuming physical scientists are amazing truth-seeking ubermenschen is just stupid.
He and his colleagues have developed a simulink-like application for stock-flow consistent modeling of the macroeconomy. And he's had some important insights from very simple models. He's able to easily switch between the "loanable funds" and "endogenous money" models of lending, for example, and show the consequences of lending to the greater economy under those models. He developed that example in order to get neoclassical economists, like Krugman, to abandoned their fallicious loanable funds model, which multiple central banks have stated quite clearly is flat out wrong.
No I was not, but I’m looking into it right now. I built flow/stock models to help my company’s decision-making processes a few years ago after being exposed to them at a convention in 2012.
I’d say it proves that cryptocurrencies that do not allow fractional reserve banking are just rehashes (no pun intended) of old & discredited bimetallic/gold standard/specie/mercantilist ways of thinking.
And what further irks me about this article, and others like it, is that it does neither
- produce a result that can be observed and therefore tested. Here, the money supply distribution is not observed in the real world and is not supposed to represent observables such as wealth.
- Nor does the article start from principles of human interaction, trying then to aggregate. Whether talking about exchange or debt, the article assumes "particles" randomly gamble against each other. In fact, social norms, externalities, TIME and timing, herd behavior and boundedly rational strategizing is precisely why human behavior does not aggregate to a gambling distribution.
I know this article is from 2000, but my outlook would not have been different back then.
To my knowledge, econophysics - despite the strong marketing effort - has yet to produce new insights into the actual economy (and it has been going on since the at least twenty years).
Has econo-anything produced new insights into the economy over the last twenty years? I'm not an economics professor, so I'm not totally emerged in the literature, but it doesn't seem to be the case from my vantage point.
I'd say that behavioural economics is the field that has made the greatest progress over the past one/two decades (though it pains me profoundly to say so because it's the furthest removed from my area of the discipline).
Honestly, from my perspective (trained as a psychologist), behavioural economics is essentially running social psychology experiments on economic behvaiour.
While it's great that economists have finally abandoned rational actors, it's not really news to the rest of the social science world.
To me reads like the first premise is already wrong: "In a closed economic system, money is conserved."
The opposite is true. Debt and the loan asset (if that's correct English usage) are created from nothing, for the debtor and the creditor respectively; the loan is converted to money intermittently by the central bank. On maturity of the loan contract both liability and asset side disappear when the loan is being repaid.*
The central bank creates the money in the instant it interacts with the creditor, and when the contract ends, the money is erased.
Do I missread this in some way?
* If you disregard the interest, which is extremely simplifying obviously; still taking it into account wouldn't make the first statement more true
I would still say money is conserved, in the same sense that charge is conserved in physics. Sure, you can create electrons by pair production, but you always create positrons with them. See also the Dirac Sea.
With money, you always create debt and loan together. And yes, both can "move around" like a currency, just like electrons and holes (missing electrons) can move around in a solid, or electrons and positrons can move around in free space.
"Primary" money - I don't know if there is an economic term - is strictly conserved. It's almost sacrosanct in our society, nobody would ever just create money. Even when they talk about printing money, it's always through loans (ultimately from the central banks), and never by actually throwing on the press. Also, destruction of money is extremely rare - mostly it is devaluation of assets, but rarely somebody burning cash etc..
First, there are all sorts of different "moneys". There's official definitions of M0 to M3, but those are just categories. Manner of payment is achieved in different ways, and all these things have different societal, economic and judical relationships to each other.
But speaking of the official classifications, money is not conserved or constant, can be destroyed or created and change its relationship to other categories. Ex:
https://3.bp.blogspot.com/-Dd1sW5ny2F0/Tb1e6oteMuI/AAAAAAAAB...
Where M0 is cash, and M1 are funds directly available for payment and so forth.
And while M0 is usually the most stable, not only DOES cash get created and destroyed, this is even independent of loan/debit creation (which is another measure entirely).
Central banks may call in and destroy, convert, or give out cash to banks with and without changing loans/debits and so forth, for all sorts of considerations.
Wealth is most definitely not a conserved quantity.
Think of the equity of a typical household. It includes some equity in their flat, which has a current market value. Down the street a developer buys a whole building block at a slight premium to rid itself of extant tenants and in so doing drives up the estimated value of local real-estate, including our household's equity. They've just gotten richer. They could even remortgage their house and monetise that increase in wealth. They could sell it and buy a bigger flat in another part of town.
So no: wealth is not conserved. Quantified (maybe), but definitely not conserved.
You put it out in your garage sale. A stranger comes along and offers $20 for it. Another person arrives and tells you it’s actually a valuable piece and would pay $200 for it.
A third person comes along and explains that it was made by their great grandmother and it was the last piece she made and she will pay $2000 for it. For sentimental reasons.
This third person has made a powerful enemy who then comes along and offers $20000 for the item, just to spite them. They intend to set the painting on fire.
How much “wealth” was stored in the painting?
Art is silly but really all value is subjective and situational. Crayfish can be cheap poor people food or a delicacy of the rich, depending on culture. You could die in a desert, weighed down with “valuable” gold because the traveller you met would not trade it for their last canteen of water.
This is a nice example showing how people don't really know what is going on, wealth seems to behave in very mysterious ways.
But, in each step you are clearly adding more and more context along with the physical item itself, context that must itself have some physical encoding.
My point is mainly that I insist that physical reality is all there is, and if some events are hard to assign to any one physical thing that just means we are looking for subtle correlations.
I'm pretty sure that in economics, physical reality is not all there is. Economics is about people assigning value to things. The things, by themselves, have no economic value.
Well, if you go for the position that people are just machines made of atoms, then, yes, physical reality is all there is, even in economics. But no, I do not want to start with atomic physics, and from there try to derive human utility, and from that try to derive economics. That's... not a feasible research program. It's not going to provide any insight into economics, ever.
So even if you accept the materialist position, for purposes of doing economics, you kind of have to regard humans as something different. (Or so it seems to me, a non-economist.)
Economics (like most things that aren't physicsf even lots of subfields of physics) doesn't model everything (or much of anything) it addresses in the physical universe from the base up, but it doesn't require treating anything as special and non-physical either.
I feel that the clue is really in the name, wealth is stored “value”, and value is well, a “value judgement”.
If you have to strip away all uncertainty from the universe to support your position and further posit hard materialism and then qualify with “in practice it’s not discoverable but philosophically it’s there” then I feel we are squarely in angels dancing on pinheads territory.
Physics itself does not need such violent axioms to get useful results! I think you would be hard pressed to find a physicist who would claim a plausible conservation law for “subjective beauty” (another kind of value), yet this is also a consequence of your premises.
You’ve explained that you are a materialist but not really anything useful about economics as practised by humans. Who are, perforce, rather limited.
You could equally well say “there is a ‘true’ value for every thing, but only god knows it”. That statement would be exactly as useful and (as an aside) just as unprovable a belief.
If we are in dancing angels territory it is because you insist that counting angels on pinheads is exactly how you value cheeseburgers. Meanwhile, I will stick to the notion that the value of a cheeseburger is tied to how hungry I am and if I've got other stuff to do.
The things that can be owned are not necessarily physical. Think of intellectual property, which is essentially information about the permutations into which that physical matter can be arranged, and you'll notice that there's a huge excess of potential ownership. Financial derivatives are similarly only very loosely related to the world of material, and yet they account for trillions of dollars’ worth.
Ok, so basically you're saying that one can own arbitrary bits of phase space?
But does this really give you non-conservation? Doesn't your remark just clarify that non-conservation comes from ignoring most of the space of possible ownership until someone bothers to go there?
I mean, there is clearly a difference between the value of (sensible) financial derivatives and the value of the death star to the imperial court in the Star wars universe.
So the connection to physical reality clearly matters somehow.
I'm arguing a bit more, actually: that the phase-space itself can form the basis for higher-abstraction phase-spaces, and so on almost ad infinitum, and thus provide an almost inexhaustible supply of potential ownership.
A meta-fund that owns equity in a fund that invests in securities issued by owners of multiple pop-culture IP franchises? No problem.
What is a higher-abstraction phase space? For me the natural interpretation would be something that encodes phase space in a smaller representation, but that is clearly not what you have in mind...
In any case, I don't see why positions and correlations between different particles shouldn't be considered "real", so that's arbitrary stacking of ownership brought down to earth.
In fact, wasn't subprime to a large degree about falsely claimed correlations? That is to say the derivatives implicitly assumed things that weren't true, or in other words secretly left reality behind.
Not sure what you mean by "primary" money, but I can't think of a definition that would make that statement ("is strictly conserved") true.
All money is in the books of the central bank, and it all has counterpart assets to it, and is all based on contracts with a maturity of less than a year. So if no-one renews there is no money, regardless of definition, in circulation after that time.
Edit. Coin would be the only exception, but that's a negligibly small item in the balance.
In this context, closed system is term used in statistical mechanics that says that there are quantities (energy and particles) that may not enter or leave the system. So I would read this is 'if we assume that money plays the role of energy in statistical mechanics, what happens'.
I was a theoretical physicist when this paper came out. I remember talking to some econphysicists at the time, though neither of these two. While as a premise, it probably doesn't stand up to much scrutiny, I think the spirit is that even if one makes such a drastic assumption, can one still observe any observable features of actual economic systems.
You describe an economic system that is not closed, as you describe money being created. The simulations were run assuming a closed economic system, with debt either ignored or handled in some atypical ways.
They might have worded that a bit differently, like saying "We assume a simplified economic system that has constant money". Because "closed economic systems" with this meaning don't exist in real life.
Closed systems don't exist in reality either. You can try to shield from radiation including cosmic microwave background but you can't from gravity.
Research on closed systems is often directly applicable and therefore interesting. In some cases the externalities are sufficiently small, in others they're fast and the systems is essentially closed between them happening.
The first sentence of the abstract which you quoted defines what a closed system would be in economics. Closed systems are a common concept, and expecting someone to read more than one sentence to find out their methodology is reasonable.
I think the trick is that banks can issue loans for higher amounts than they have assets, but if you sum up all the assets and liabilities, the sum should stay constant. So the conservation works more like an electrical potential, where you can always go lower locally, rather than a number of atoms, which has a fixed minimum at 0.
I.e. the creator creates an asset. The asset is then used as collateral for a loan. The loan is simply a notation in a ledger. Money is created when the loan is spent. Money is destroyed when the loan is paid off.
The money isn't destroyed though -- it's converted into wealth as an asset.
A bank provides a loan to Andy for $100 to build a house. Andy builds the house worth $100. Once the house is paid off, the bank gets $100+interest, and Andy has a house worth some amount relative to that $100.
The $100 never disappears as a result of the loan. Whether or not the bank then chooses to destroy the money once the loan is repaid is not really a material to the discussion. Replace "bank" with "parents" and it's clear that no money is destroyed as a result of the loan.
What you're talking about is really just a side-effect of our accounting practices and/or asserting that all lending originates from the Central Bank.
The money appears and disappears as the result of fractional reserve banking. The analogy with your parents loaning you the money is incorrect because your parents cannot engage in fractional reserve monetary creation.
It actually has nothing to do with the central bank - fractional reserve banking has a much longer history than central banking.
You never specified that loans must come from entities with reserve requirements. Not all loans originate from such entities so your statement should not be taken as absolute fact.
He says:
"All money is in the books of the central bank,[..]"
In the case of lending, it's the commercial banks where the money is created and destroyed. If enough reserves exist already in the system the central bank don't need to act.
That's true depending on the definition of money you use. Commercial banks can't create central bank money (M0). But they can create credit, and convert it to central bank money at will. And credit counts into M1+, one of the common money supply indicators.
I'd say "money" in common usage is only M0 (central bank lines) and MB (notes and coin), and the others are only technical indicators used by economists. But that's debatable.
People exchange real labour, houses and cars mostly using those "technical indicators". (Few people buy a house or car with notes and coins or with their central bank line.)
he describes the monetary/credit/debit system in the same way, and I do agree the first premise is suspect depending on how you define "closed system".
However, I assume the authors' rebuttal would be that real-world economic systems are not closed system. Not that it makes their claims any more applicable to the real world.
To elaborate on "interesting things", at least as I understood it from a seminar by one of the authors...
- The distribution of wealth naturally forms an exponential distribution. It takes effort/energy/negentropy to depart from this situation where there will always be many more poor people than rich.
- Unlike particle energy, wealth can be negative. When this is accounted for (allow for debt), the rich inherently get richer. This is not even accounting for interest being paid by the debtors to the (presumably rich) debtees.
- At a certain point, money begets more money. This results in a power law tail and identifies the "upper class".
Physicists have gotten very good at the statistics of interacting particles. This paper asks, what if instead of a bunch of particles exchanging energy, one interprets it as the theory of many agents randonly exchanging money. Interesting things happen even in this over-simplified model.
Is it possible that the poorer factions in a society learn skillsets that are keeping them poor? Their skillsets help them through poor life but are prolly useless when getting more money?
If any of these things - and these things being what distinguishes social interactions and human behavior from particles - were the case, we'd have "solved" our economic modeling issues long ago.
From my perspective (economist with prior math background), what makes the economic interaction of humans interesting and hard, is precisely that these interactions can not be aggregated (in a well-defined manner) to simple statistical or behavioral laws - be it distributions or representations, even if certain outcome distributions are observable.
To my knowledge, econophysics - despite the strong marketing effort - has yet to produce new insights into the actual economy (and it has been going on since the at least twenty years).
I think this is not surprising. The economics research effort does not lack in mathematical sophistication, even if physicists like to believe that. In fact, in terms of strategic interaction, behavioral patterns and epistemology, I think the economic models are well ahead of physics models for describing behavior. But - no one is really all that close if the level of aggregation is high. That means, macroeconomics and matters of money supply.